Marketplace realities get lost in class certification “shortcut”
Historically, certification of a purchaser class has relied on a demonstration that class members were exposed to, relied on and were directly harmed by the alleged fraud or misrepresentation. Over time, however, approaches to class certification have evolved.
October 15, 2012 at 08:04 AM
10 minute read
The original version of this story was published on Law.com
Class certification is a key step in consumer fraud and false advertising class actions. Historically, certification of a purchaser class has relied on a demonstration that class members were exposed to, relied on and were directly harmed by the alleged fraud or misrepresentation (e.g., by purchasing a product they would not have otherwise purchased or getting less value from a product than was implicitly promised). Over time, however, approaches to class certification have evolved. In the past few years, there have been several cases in which plaintiffs have argued that the court should accept a “shortcut” to this showing of direct harm through reliance and exposure.
In these cases, plaintiffs have claimed that all class members were harmed because the conduct at issue increased the prices all purchasers paid, including those who were not exposed to or did not rely on any allegedly misleading information and who would not have changed their purchasing decisions with different information. Plaintiffs have argued that the fraud or false advertising affected the perceptions and conduct of enough consumers to increase demand for the product, resulting in a price higher than it would have been absent the conduct at issue. In a world without the alleged fraud or misrepresentation, the plaintiffs claim, prices would be lower and the alleged difference between actual and but-for prices will harm all purchasers, whether or not each of them was exposed to and/or relied on the alleged misinformation. If a court were to accept the logic of this shortcut approach, there would be no need to assess either individual exposure or reliance, nor to determine whether individual purchase decisions and prices paid were impacted.
This “fraud on the market” type argument, however, relies on a number of assumptions about the economic features of the market that might not hold. First, the argument requires that an increase in demand will lead to an increase in price in the market at issue. Yet this is not always the case. In some industries, or for some products, prices remain flat or even decline when the total quantity sold increases. In some high-tech industries, for example, prices fall as a technology is more widely adopted because increasing returns to scale or “learning by doing” causes production costs to fall as quantities rise. An increase in demand could accelerate price reductions as firms are able to achieve quantity-related cost reductions more quickly. As a result, an increase in demand could benefit some consumers through lower prices. Another reason that prices may not rise with an increase in demand is that prices for some goods are “sticky” due to the costs associated with changing prices. As these two examples show, it is critical to assess the actual relationship between prices and demand in the relevant marketplace; one cannot simply assume the relationship.
Another market feature that is necessary for the shortcut class certification approach to apply is that there be a single price for the product or, if various customer groups are charged different prices, that these prices move together. Again, while some markets exhibit this type of pricing, others do not. It is not unusual for producers to charge different customer groups different prices based on differences in their sensitivity to price or their bargaining power. In these cases, changes in demand for one customer group will not necessarily affect the price the producer charges another customer group. For example, business purchasers may be both more price-sensitive and more knowledgeable about true product characteristics than consumers. If business customers are more price-sensitive, they may pay a lower price for the product than consumer purchasers. If they are more sophisticated purchasers, the alleged misrepresentation may also not affect their perception of, and demand for, the product. As a result, the prices businesses pay might not be affected even in a case in which the alleged misinformation inflated consumer demand. Similarly, individually negotiated prices can lead to instances in which some, but not all, customers pay higher prices as a result of an alleged misrepresentation.
A third economic assumption necessary to support the shortcut approach, and the last discussed here, is that the harm of paying a higher price is not offset by other benefits to the purchaser that the conduct also caused. The key impact question is whether in a but-for world without the alleged misrepresentation or fraud, an individual purchaser is better off. Depending on the allegation, some purchasers could be better off even if the alleged misrepresentation has caused them to pay a higher price than they would have paid absent the conduct. For example, plaintiffs may claim that the manufacturer of a consumer product should have disclosed a potential health risk associated with its use. Had the company made this disclosure, some purchasers might have chosen another product that was in fact less well-suited to their overall needs (taking into account effectiveness, price, actual health risks or other features). Those members of the proposed class could be better off paying an allegedly inflated price and purchasing the product at issue, than they would have been purchasing another product. This example demonstrates why one cannot generally skip the step of determining what each consumer would have purchased in the but-for world when assessing harm.
In summary, although the shortcut approach has some theoretical appeal, its applicability depends on the details of the marketplace. Although plaintiffs often ask the court to simply assume that higher demand leads to higher prices for all purchasers and higher prices inevitably mean overall harm, there are economic features present in many markets that mean these assumptions do not hold.
The views expressed in this article are solely those of the authors, who are responsible for the content, and do not necessarily represent the views of Cornerstone Research.
Class certification is a key step in consumer fraud and false advertising class actions. Historically, certification of a purchaser class has relied on a demonstration that class members were exposed to, relied on and were directly harmed by the alleged fraud or misrepresentation (e.g., by purchasing a product they would not have otherwise purchased or getting less value from a product than was implicitly promised). Over time, however, approaches to class certification have evolved. In the past few years, there have been several cases in which plaintiffs have argued that the court should accept a “shortcut” to this showing of direct harm through reliance and exposure.
In these cases, plaintiffs have claimed that all class members were harmed because the conduct at issue increased the prices all purchasers paid, including those who were not exposed to or did not rely on any allegedly misleading information and who would not have changed their purchasing decisions with different information. Plaintiffs have argued that the fraud or false advertising affected the perceptions and conduct of enough consumers to increase demand for the product, resulting in a price higher than it would have been absent the conduct at issue. In a world without the alleged fraud or misrepresentation, the plaintiffs claim, prices would be lower and the alleged difference between actual and but-for prices will harm all purchasers, whether or not each of them was exposed to and/or relied on the alleged misinformation. If a court were to accept the logic of this shortcut approach, there would be no need to assess either individual exposure or reliance, nor to determine whether individual purchase decisions and prices paid were impacted.
This “fraud on the market” type argument, however, relies on a number of assumptions about the economic features of the market that might not hold. First, the argument requires that an increase in demand will lead to an increase in price in the market at issue. Yet this is not always the case. In some industries, or for some products, prices remain flat or even decline when the total quantity sold increases. In some high-tech industries, for example, prices fall as a technology is more widely adopted because increasing returns to scale or “learning by doing” causes production costs to fall as quantities rise. An increase in demand could accelerate price reductions as firms are able to achieve quantity-related cost reductions more quickly. As a result, an increase in demand could benefit some consumers through lower prices. Another reason that prices may not rise with an increase in demand is that prices for some goods are “sticky” due to the costs associated with changing prices. As these two examples show, it is critical to assess the actual relationship between prices and demand in the relevant marketplace; one cannot simply assume the relationship.
Another market feature that is necessary for the shortcut class certification approach to apply is that there be a single price for the product or, if various customer groups are charged different prices, that these prices move together. Again, while some markets exhibit this type of pricing, others do not. It is not unusual for producers to charge different customer groups different prices based on differences in their sensitivity to price or their bargaining power. In these cases, changes in demand for one customer group will not necessarily affect the price the producer charges another customer group. For example, business purchasers may be both more price-sensitive and more knowledgeable about true product characteristics than consumers. If business customers are more price-sensitive, they may pay a lower price for the product than consumer purchasers. If they are more sophisticated purchasers, the alleged misrepresentation may also not affect their perception of, and demand for, the product. As a result, the prices businesses pay might not be affected even in a case in which the alleged misinformation inflated consumer demand. Similarly, individually negotiated prices can lead to instances in which some, but not all, customers pay higher prices as a result of an alleged misrepresentation.
A third economic assumption necessary to support the shortcut approach, and the last discussed here, is that the harm of paying a higher price is not offset by other benefits to the purchaser that the conduct also caused. The key impact question is whether in a but-for world without the alleged misrepresentation or fraud, an individual purchaser is better off. Depending on the allegation, some purchasers could be better off even if the alleged misrepresentation has caused them to pay a higher price than they would have paid absent the conduct. For example, plaintiffs may claim that the manufacturer of a consumer product should have disclosed a potential health risk associated with its use. Had the company made this disclosure, some purchasers might have chosen another product that was in fact less well-suited to their overall needs (taking into account effectiveness, price, actual health risks or other features). Those members of the proposed class could be better off paying an allegedly inflated price and purchasing the product at issue, than they would have been purchasing another product. This example demonstrates why one cannot generally skip the step of determining what each consumer would have purchased in the but-for world when assessing harm.
In summary, although the shortcut approach has some theoretical appeal, its applicability depends on the details of the marketplace. Although plaintiffs often ask the court to simply assume that higher demand leads to higher prices for all purchasers and higher prices inevitably mean overall harm, there are economic features present in many markets that mean these assumptions do not hold.
The views expressed in this article are solely those of the authors, who are responsible for the content, and do not necessarily represent the views of Cornerstone Research.
This content has been archived. It is available through our partners, LexisNexis® and Bloomberg Law.
To view this content, please continue to their sites.
Not a Lexis Subscriber?
Subscribe Now
Not a Bloomberg Law Subscriber?
Subscribe Now
NOT FOR REPRINT
© 2025 ALM Global, LLC, All Rights Reserved. Request academic re-use from www.copyright.com. All other uses, submit a request to [email protected]. For more information visit Asset & Logo Licensing.
You Might Like
View All![Recent Controversial Decision and Insurance Law May Mitigate Exposure for Companies Subject to False Claims Act Lawsuits Recent Controversial Decision and Insurance Law May Mitigate Exposure for Companies Subject to False Claims Act Lawsuits](https://images.law.com/cdn-cgi/image/format=auto,fit=contain/https://k2-prod-alm.s3.us-east-1.amazonaws.com/brightspot/fd/84/3d7fb4d146d38b97cfab7af5b7c7/inside-feature-767x633-2.jpg)
Recent Controversial Decision and Insurance Law May Mitigate Exposure for Companies Subject to False Claims Act Lawsuits
7 minute read![Varsity Brands Lures Aboard Keurig Dr. Pepper Legal Chief Varsity Brands Lures Aboard Keurig Dr. Pepper Legal Chief](https://images.law.com/cdn-cgi/image/format=auto,fit=contain/https://k2-prod-alm.s3.us-east-1.amazonaws.com/brightspot/83/dc/a59e06ad42be872191fe7a086901/cheerleaders-767x633.jpg)
![Hasbro Faces Shareholder Ire Over 'Excessive' Toy, Game Inventory Hasbro Faces Shareholder Ire Over 'Excessive' Toy, Game Inventory](https://images.law.com/cdn-cgi/image/format=auto,fit=contain/https://k2-prod-alm.s3.us-east-1.amazonaws.com/brightspot/68/d7/ef03ff8a4ced831763f57095d82f/hasbro-767x633.jpg)
![CLOs Face Mounting Pressure as Risks Mushroom and Job Duties Expand CLOs Face Mounting Pressure as Risks Mushroom and Job Duties Expand](https://images.law.com/cdn-cgi/image/format=auto,fit=contain/https://images.law.com/corpcounsel/contrib/content/uploads/sites/390/2023/10/Businessman-juggling-business-icons-767x633.jpg)
Trending Stories
- 1Parties’ Reservation of Rights Defeats Attempt to Enforce Settlement in Principle
- 2ACC CLO Survey Waves Warning Flags for Boards
- 3States Accuse Trump of Thwarting Court's Funding Restoration Order
- 4Microsoft Becomes Latest Tech Company to Face Claims of Stealing Marketing Commissions From Influencers
- 5Coral Gables Attorney Busted for Stalking Lawyer
Who Got The Work
J. Brugh Lower of Gibbons has entered an appearance for industrial equipment supplier Devco Corporation in a pending trademark infringement lawsuit. The suit, accusing the defendant of selling knock-off Graco products, was filed Dec. 18 in New Jersey District Court by Rivkin Radler on behalf of Graco Inc. and Graco Minnesota. The case, assigned to U.S. District Judge Zahid N. Quraishi, is 3:24-cv-11294, Graco Inc. et al v. Devco Corporation.
Who Got The Work
Rebecca Maller-Stein and Kent A. Yalowitz of Arnold & Porter Kaye Scholer have entered their appearances for Hanaco Venture Capital and its executives, Lior Prosor and David Frankel, in a pending securities lawsuit. The action, filed on Dec. 24 in New York Southern District Court by Zell, Aron & Co. on behalf of Goldeneye Advisors, accuses the defendants of negligently and fraudulently managing the plaintiff's $1 million investment. The case, assigned to U.S. District Judge Vernon S. Broderick, is 1:24-cv-09918, Goldeneye Advisors, LLC v. Hanaco Venture Capital, Ltd. et al.
Who Got The Work
Attorneys from A&O Shearman has stepped in as defense counsel for Toronto-Dominion Bank and other defendants in a pending securities class action. The suit, filed Dec. 11 in New York Southern District Court by Bleichmar Fonti & Auld, accuses the defendants of concealing the bank's 'pervasive' deficiencies in regards to its compliance with the Bank Secrecy Act and the quality of its anti-money laundering controls. The case, assigned to U.S. District Judge Arun Subramanian, is 1:24-cv-09445, Gonzalez v. The Toronto-Dominion Bank et al.
Who Got The Work
Crown Castle International, a Pennsylvania company providing shared communications infrastructure, has turned to Luke D. Wolf of Gordon Rees Scully Mansukhani to fend off a pending breach-of-contract lawsuit. The court action, filed Nov. 25 in Michigan Eastern District Court by Hooper Hathaway PC on behalf of The Town Residences LLC, accuses Crown Castle of failing to transfer approximately $30,000 in utility payments from T-Mobile in breach of a roof-top lease and assignment agreement. The case, assigned to U.S. District Judge Susan K. Declercq, is 2:24-cv-13131, The Town Residences LLC v. T-Mobile US, Inc. et al.
Who Got The Work
Wilfred P. Coronato and Daniel M. Schwartz of McCarter & English have stepped in as defense counsel to Electrolux Home Products Inc. in a pending product liability lawsuit. The court action, filed Nov. 26 in New York Eastern District Court by Poulos Lopiccolo PC and Nagel Rice LLP on behalf of David Stern, alleges that the defendant's refrigerators’ drawers and shelving repeatedly break and fall apart within months after purchase. The case, assigned to U.S. District Judge Joan M. Azrack, is 2:24-cv-08204, Stern v. Electrolux Home Products, Inc.
Featured Firms
Law Offices of Gary Martin Hays & Associates, P.C.
(470) 294-1674
Law Offices of Mark E. Salomone
(857) 444-6468
Smith & Hassler
(713) 739-1250